@article{Apelojg2016, author = {Apelojg, Benjamin}, title = {Lehrer machen keine Fehler! Zusammenh{\"a}nge zwischen Lehrpers{\"o}nlichkeit und Seminarpraxis}, series = {Das Theorie-Praxis-Verh{\"a}ltnis in der {\"o}konomischen Bildung}, journal = {Das Theorie-Praxis-Verh{\"a}ltnis in der {\"o}konomischen Bildung}, editor = {Holger, Arndt}, publisher = {Wochenschau Verlag}, address = {Schwalbach/Ts}, isbn = {978-3-7344-0218-0}, pages = {269 -- 278}, year = {2016}, language = {de} } @article{KalkuhlEdenhofer2016, author = {Kalkuhl, Matthias and Edenhofer, Ottmar}, title = {Ramsey meets Th{\"u}nen}, series = {International tax and public finance}, volume = {24}, journal = {International tax and public finance}, publisher = {Springer}, address = {Dordrecht}, issn = {0927-5940}, doi = {10.1007/s10797-016-9403-6}, pages = {350 -- 380}, year = {2016}, abstract = {Land taxes can increase production in the manufacturing sector and enhance land conservation at the same time, which can lead to overall macroeconomic growth. Existing research emphasizes the non-distorting properties of land taxes (when fixed factors are taxed) as well as growth-enhancing impacts (when asset portfolios are shifted to reproducible capital). This paper furthers the neoclassical perspective on land taxes by endogenizing land allocation decisions in a multi-sector growth model. Based on von Th{\"u}nen's observation, agricultural land is created from wilderness through conversion and cultivation, both of which are associated with costs. In the steady state of our general equilibrium model, land taxes not only may reduce land consumption (associated with environmental benefits) but may also affect overall economic output, while leaving wages and interest rates unaffected. When labor productivity is higher in the manufacturing than in the agricultural sector and agricultural and manufactured goods are substitutes (or the economy is open to world trade), land taxes increase aggregate economic output. There is a complex interplay of conservation policy, technological change and land taxes, depending on consumer preferences, sectoral labor productivities and openness-to-trade. Our model introduces a new perspective on land taxes in current policy debates on development, tax reforms as well as forest conservation.}, language = {en} } @article{Orland2016, author = {Orland, Andreas}, title = {Personality traits and the perception of macroeconomic indicators}, series = {Bulletin of Economic Research}, volume = {69}, journal = {Bulletin of Economic Research}, number = {4}, publisher = {Wiley}, address = {Hoboken}, issn = {0307-3378}, doi = {10.1111/boer.12110}, pages = {E150 -- E172}, year = {2016}, abstract = {I examine the determinants of both perceived inflation and unemployment in one single survey and include Big Five traits in the analysis. This is the first survey on this topic in Germany. My sample consists of 1771 students from different fields and levels. Using PhD students' estimates as a reference, I create categories for underestimation and overestimation of both variables. Multinomial logit regressions show that females overestimate both variables. Education and news consumption reduce misestimation. A higher level of Neuroticism is related with a higher probability to overestimate unemployment. Overstating (understating) one indicator is associated with overstating (understating) the other.}, language = {en} } @article{VogelKroll2016, author = {Vogel, Dominik and Kroll, Alexander}, title = {The stability and change of psm-related values across time}, series = {International public management journal}, volume = {19}, journal = {International public management journal}, publisher = {J. C. B. Mohr}, address = {Abingdon}, issn = {1096-7494}, doi = {10.1080/10967494.2015.1047544}, pages = {53 -- 77}, year = {2016}, abstract = {This article is a response to calls in prior research that we need more longitudinal analyses to better understand the foundations of PSM and related prosocial values. There is wide agreement that it is crucial for theory building but also for tailoring hiring practices and human resource development programs to sort out whether PSM-related values are stable or developable. The article summarizes existent theoretical expectations, which turn out to be partially conflicting, and tests them against multiple waves of data from the German Socio-Economic Panel Study which covers a time period of 16 years. It finds that PSM-related values of public employees are stable rather than dynamic but tend to increase with age and decrease with organizational membership. The article also examines cohort effects, which have been neglected in prior work, and finds moderate evidence that there are differences between those born during the Second World War and later generations.}, language = {en} } @article{Reichard2016, author = {Reichard, Christoph}, title = {Can training help to make politicians more active users of performance information?}, series = {Bio-medical materials and engineering : an international journal}, volume = {36}, journal = {Bio-medical materials and engineering : an international journal}, publisher = {IOS Press}, address = {Abingdon}, issn = {0954-0962}, doi = {10.1080/09540962.2016.1237119}, pages = {481 -- 482}, year = {2016}, language = {en} } @article{BraunBockelmann2016, author = {Braun, Andreas and Bockelmann, Laura}, title = {An individual perspective on open innovation capabilities in the context of haute cuisine}, series = {International journal of innovation in management}, volume = {20}, journal = {International journal of innovation in management}, publisher = {World Scientific}, address = {Singapore}, issn = {1363-9196}, doi = {10.1142/S136391961650002X}, pages = {480 -- 499}, year = {2016}, abstract = {Previous research on open innovation (OI) has primarily focused on the organisational level of R\&D intensive industries. With this paper, we contribute to research on the individual level of analysis by analysing specific perspectives in the context of creative industries. Our study is based on 36 interviews with Haute cuisine chefs in France, Germany, Great Britain, Italy, Spain, Sweden, and Switzerland listed in the 2012 Michelin Guide. Building on the OI capability concept, our results demonstrate that chefs use absorptive and desorptive capacity (AC, DC) as means to generate and market culinary innovations, respectively. Moreover, we found that chefs almost exclusively rely on their own inventive and innovative capabilities in the early stages of the culinary innovation process. In subsequent phases, however, chefs increasingly integrate other sources such as employees, suppliers, and guests. Our study contributes to the literature in two ways. First, we research the individual level within the OI process, and second, we provide insight into OI practices in the creative industries.}, language = {en} } @article{ErmakovaFabianZarnekow2016, author = {Ermakova, Tatiana and Fabian, Benjamin and Zarnekow, Ruediger}, title = {Improving Individual Acceptance of Health Clouds through Confidentiality Assurance}, series = {Applied clinical informatics}, volume = {7}, journal = {Applied clinical informatics}, publisher = {Schattauer}, address = {Stuttgart}, issn = {1869-0327}, doi = {10.4338/ACI-2016-07-RA-0107}, pages = {983 -- 993}, year = {2016}, abstract = {Background: Cloud computing promises to essentially improve healthcare delivery performance. However, shifting sensitive medical records to third-party cloud providers could create an adoption hurdle because of security and privacy concerns. Methods: We empirically investigate our research question by a survey with over 260 full responses. For the setting with a high confidentiality assurance, we base on a recent multi-cloud architecture which provides very high confidentiality assurance through a secret-sharing mechanism: Health information is cryptographically encoded and distributed in a way that no single and no small group of cloud providers is able to decode it.}, language = {en} } @article{Wenzel2016, author = {Wenzel, Bertolt}, title = {Organizing coordination in a public marine research and management advice organization: The case of the Norwegian Institute of Marine Research}, series = {Marine policy}, volume = {64}, journal = {Marine policy}, publisher = {Elsevier}, address = {Oxford}, issn = {0308-597X}, doi = {10.1016/j.marpol.2015.11.017}, pages = {159 -- 167}, year = {2016}, abstract = {Public organizations involved in marine management are increasingly confronted with coordination challenges in marine governance. This study examines why and how the Norwegian Institute of Marine Research (IMR) reorganized its formal coordination structures between the areas of fisheries management and marine environmental management The findings indicate that organizing efficient and, at the same time, legitimate coordination structures between different areas of marine governance is a "wicked" organizational problem with no ultimate and single optimal solution. In contrast to the assumptions of classical organization and management theory, the study finds that the reorganization of formal coordination structures is not necessarily driven for reasons of efficiency and perceived coordination problems. Instead, public marine management organizations also change their organizational structures to live up to external expectations to adopt modern management concepts, such as the Ecosystem Approach to Management (EAM). However, the study indicates that the adoption of the EAM has stimulated coordination and integration efforts in the research and advisory activities of the IMR. (C) 2015 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.}, language = {en} } @article{NeumannNieswandSchubert2016, author = {Neumann, Anne and Nieswand, Maria and Schubert, Torben}, title = {Estimating alternative technology sets in nonparametric efficiency analysis: restriction tests for panel and clustered data}, series = {Journal of productivity analysis}, volume = {45}, journal = {Journal of productivity analysis}, publisher = {Springer}, address = {Dordrecht}, issn = {0895-562X}, doi = {10.1007/s11123-015-0461-z}, pages = {35 -- 51}, year = {2016}, abstract = {Nonparametric efficiency analysis has become a widely applied technique to support industrial bench-marking as well as a variety of incentive-based regulation policies. In practice such exercises are often plagued by incomplete knowledge about the correct specifications of inputs and outputs. Simar and Wilson (Commun Stat Simul Comput 30(1): 159-184, 2001) and Schubert and Simar (J Prod Anal 36(1): 55-69, 2011) propose restriction tests to support such specification decisions for cross-section data. However, the typical oligopolized market structure pertinent to regulation contexts often leads to low numbers of cross-section observations, rendering reliable estimation based on these tests practically unfeasible. This small-sample problem could often be avoided with the use of panel data, which would in any case require an extension of the cross-section restriction tests to handle panel data. In this paper we derive these tests. We prove the consistency of the proposed method and apply it to a sample of US natural gas transmission companies from 2003 through 2007. We find that the total quantity of natural gas delivered and natural gas delivered in peak periods measure essentially the same output. Therefore only one needs to be included. We also show that the length of mains as a measure of transportation service is non-redundant and therefore must be included.}, language = {en} } @article{OrlandSelten2016, author = {Orland, Andreas and Selten, Reinhard}, title = {Buyer power in bilateral oligopolies with advance production: Experimental evidence}, series = {Applied surface science : a journal devoted to applied physics and chemistry of surfaces and interfaces}, volume = {122}, journal = {Applied surface science : a journal devoted to applied physics and chemistry of surfaces and interfaces}, publisher = {Elsevier}, address = {Amsterdam}, issn = {0167-2681}, doi = {10.1016/j.jebo.2015.11.016}, pages = {31 -- 42}, year = {2016}, abstract = {We conduct experiments based on the oligopoly model by Kreps and Scheinkman (1983) to assess the impact of demand side concentration on market outcomes. Both buyers and sellers in our markets are humans. The number of firms is fixed at three in all treatments. Only the number of buyers is varied and total demand is split equally among them. We observe that firms set lower prices in markets with only few buyers, namely one or two. Price dispersion is higher in markets with few buyers. Aggregate demand withholding decreases with the number of buyers. This results in lower profits for firms and higher profits for buyers in markets with few buyers. (C) 2015 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.}, language = {en} }